CIRCEE: Difference between revisions

From CIRCOMOD Stylized Model Wiki
No edit summary
No edit summary
 
(127 intermediate revisions by 2 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
=== General Scope and Connection with Climate Mitigation ===
== General Scope and Connection with Climate Mitigation ==


* <big>Introduction</big>
=== Introduction ===
Assessing the full potential of a circular economy requires a macro-level and integrated assessment approach that addresses the complex interdependencies and trade-offs between environmental, social, and economic objectives. Policy support, lifestyle changes, innovation, and new business models such as sharing and digitalization models are critical enablers for the transition to a circular economy, as well as a deep understanding of the underlying drivers and barriers. Also, it is important to understand the hypothetical synergies, benefits and trade-offs with implementing different circular economy strategies As these policies and lifestyle changes are vital in driving the transition toward a circular economy, understanding their implications is essential. Assessing the impact of a CE on socioeconomic systems remains a complex and challenging task for Integrated Assessment Models and the macroeconomic modeling community. Pauliuk et al. (2017) emphasize the necessity of incorporating industrial ecology system linkages into Integrated Assessment Models.


The decarbonization of our production processes and consumption of habits have a key role to play in achieving climate targets. One effective way to achieve this is by shifting from a linear economic system to a circular one, which emphasizes resource efficiency and reducing GreenHouse Gases emissions. The integration of circular economy poses many challenges to the Integrated Assessment Models (IAMs) modeling community, including accounting for physical material flows, thermodynamics limits, and waste flows. CIRCEE (''CIRC''ular ''E''nergy ''E''conomy), developed by the RFF-CMCC European Institute on Economics and the Environment, addresses these challenges by developing a stylized dynamic model. The stylized model will serve as a modeling starting point for the IAM community and will help mapping circular economy strategies into the existing climate scenarios. 
[[CIRCEE]] (''CIRC''ular ''E''nergy ''E''conomy), developed by the [https://www.eiee.org RFF-CMCC European Institute on Economics and the Environment], addresses these challenges by developing a stylized DSGE model, soft-linked to the [https://www.witchmodel.org WITCH integrated assessment model] and the LIFE model of Pettifor, Wilson, and Agnew (2023)<ref name=":0">Hazel Pettifor, Maureen Agnew, Charlie Wilson. ''A framework for measuring and modelling low-carbon lifestyles,'' Global Environmental Change, Volume 82, 2023, 102739, ISSN 0959-3780, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2023.102739.</ref>, that integrates some industrial ecology aspects and lifestyle heterogeneity. Our framework captures the dynamic feedback loops between physical and economic systems and assesses the trade-offs and synergies between different sustainability objectives. The stylized model will serve as a starting point for the {{abbr|Integrated Assessment Model|IAM}} community and help map CE strategies into existing climate scenarios.
 
* <big>Model Scope.</big>  
CIRCEE is a stylized dynamic general equilibrium model that monitors physical material and waste stock/flows. It incorporates key industrial ecology principles to evaluate how circular economy strategies and enablers can decrease future greenhouse gas emissions and enhance resource efficiency, especially in resource-poor economies. The main focus of CIRCEE is on countries that may become relatively less reliant on resources in the the long run due to the adoption of circular economy strategies and new business models, such as the sharing economy and digitalization. CIRCEE can be shocked by many exogenous forces linked to circular economy strategies and enablers.  


The CIRCEE model is a stylized dynamic general equilibrium model that monitors material and waste flows/stocks and incorporates key elements of industrial ecology. The model integrates is aimed to take a broad perspective of circular economy strategies and enablers. The economy is populated by 3 aggregated agents, namely the households, the sectors of production and the public authority. On the household side, 3 types of households differentiated by their low-carbon lifestyles and liquidity constraints are populating the economy.  Households choose to consume different types of goods - non-durables, semi-durables, durable goods and second-hand goods - and different types of services - home-produced energy services, sharing (energy) services and repairing services. They make intra-temporal choices regarding the composition of their consumption good and services basket (e.g. consuming a sharing energy service rather than home-producing it) and inter-temporal choices from their savings and different types of assets (capital, durable and semi-durable goods, and second-hand goods). On the supply side of the economy, the economy is populated of 10 sectors producing the following products: primary (virgin) material, secondary (recycled) material, non-durable good, semi-durable good, durable good, capital good, sharing services, repairing services, second-hand (durable) good, and housing. All sectors, except the repairing and second-hand sectors, produce from labor, capital, energy (electricity and fuels), and materials (primary and secondary) inputs. The production structure of the economy is economically and physically consistent. It considers key thermodynamic limits, such as ruling-out the 100% recycling and repairing scenario, a minimal material balance condition, a thermodynamic efficiency condition, physical resources stock and flows, and volume-preserving CES functions. On the energy supply side, CIRCEE is soft linked to the IAM model WITCH from the RFF-CMCC European Institute on Economics and the Environment (EIEE) to assess the overall GHG mitigation potential of circular economy strategies. The public authority implements levies taxes, implements circular economy policies and makes public expenses. Finally, the model considers trade flows between the domestic economy and the rest of the world. The study of trade flows is important, as imports and exports of goods may have different material intensities.
===Model Scope===
[[File:Capture d’écran 2024-04-30 à 14.58.31.png|thumb|The CIRCular Energy-Economy model]]
CIRCEE is a deterministic Dynamic and Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) model with resource stock/flow consistency. It incorporates some industrial ecology principles to evaluate how CE strategies and enablers can decrease future greenhouse gas emissions and enhance resource efficiency. First, the production-side of the economy follows a standard Constant Elasticity Substitution (CES) tree (see Figure) that combines different CES nests of inputs capital, labor, energy and materials. For accounting reasons, the CES nest of material inputs that combines primary materials and secondary materials is transformed as an additive function of the two inputs à la Mensbrugghe and Peters (2016). The material additive CES function allows us to verify the mass balance condition, and track material flows in a more precise manner. Each sector of final good production obey the rule of conservation of mass. The production structure of the economy is not changed, as it still produces from a standard nested CES function of capital, labor, energy and materials. Materials entering the system must equal to material leaving the system, whether it be in the form of good exports, additions to the in-use stocks or waste disposal. Second, we ensure that a 100% recycling scenario is not feasible, so that the economy cannot recover all recyclable waste. A ‘loss’ parameter, estimated from data about recycling activities, is attached to the use of recyclable waste in the production process of secondary materials to capture the environmental loss of materials during the recycling process. In addition, there is a natural obsolescence rate of durable goods, so that durable goods cannot be repaired on and off. Raw materials are extracted from abroad and are then used for material processing that feeds the production processes of final goods in terms of primary material inputs. These final goods are then consumed and disposed of at a certain time depending on the life of the goods. The waste generated by end-uses as well as production processes can be either landfilled/incinerated or recycled. Recycled/recovered materials can be fed back to the economy to ensure a higher circularity rate or exported abroad.


The current geographical scope of CIRCEE is on Japan and South Korea. These countries are being studied first because they are among the least resource-rich economies in the OECD. Circular economy and new business models are essential for addressing climate change, improving resource security and promoting economic growth in these countries. While data availability will determine which additional OECD countries can be added to the model in the future, users may add other countries themselves, provided there is enough data to calibrate the model.  
<nowiki>**</nowiki>
[[File:Consumption tree in CIRCEE.png|thumb|Consumption tree in CIRCEE]]
[[File:Capture d’écran 2024-05-02 à 15.26.19.png|thumb|Typology of households in CIRCEE from the LIFE model of Pettifor et al. (2023)]]
The economy is populated by heterogeneous households, producing sectors and a public authority.


Users of CIRCEE can simulate the model for any desired number of years, using 2018 as the base year value, provided that the users have a clear trajectory or exogenous variables. Longer time horizon can also be run to avoid any end-of-horizon effect, but 2150 is generally sufficient. Results are usually reported for the period 2018-2100. The model has a yearly time step.
On the demand side of the economy, three types of households are differentiated by their lifestyles and liquidity constraints. Households choose to consume different types of goods: non-durables, semi-durables and durable goods, and services : home-produced energy services, sharing energy services, and repairing services. They make intratemporal choices regarding the composition of their consumption basket (e.g. consuming sharing energy service rather than producing it at home) and intertemporal choices between different types of assets available to them (capital, durable and semi-durable goods). In [[CIRCEE]], owners can make their durable goods available for rent to other individuals when they are not using them and are willing to rent them. The lifestyles are those outlined in the Pettifor, Wilson, and Agnew (2023)<ref name=":0" />. Low-carbon behaviors (lifestyles) are driven by cognitions and social/material contexts. They affect directly households' preferences in :  
[[File:Capture d’écran 2023-04-16 à 18.45.10.png|thumb|The CIRCular Energy-Economy model visual representation]]
* Model documentation: in progress. Not yet available.
* Model development status: in progress.
* Model source code (relative to milestone M24). The model uses the software platform Dynare  ([https://www.dynare.org/resources/quick_start/ https://www.dynare.org]). To run Dynare, the user needs either Matlab, Julia or GNU Octave.


=== Circular Economy Features ===
* repairing durable goods rather than buying brand new
* sharing a durable goods rather than buying brand new
* lowering expenditures in durable goods and semi-durable goods (sufficiency)
[[File:Capture d’écran 2024-05-02 à 15.30.10.png|thumb|CES tree for "new products" production sectors]]On the economy's supply side, the economy is populated by eight sectors producing the following products: primary materials, secondary materials, non-durable goods, semi-durable goods, durable goods, capital goods, sharing energy services and repairing services. All goods and services sectors, except the repairing and sharing sector, produce from labour, capital, energy (electricity and fuels), and material (primary and secondary) inputs. The repairing sector only produces repairing/refurbishing services using labor and capital. The sharing sector rents part of the durable good stock owned by households, uses energy and labor to produce sharing services. Material processing firms use labor, capital, energy and raw or waste material inputs to produce primary and secondary materials. The production structure of the economy is economically and physically consistent, in the sense that it verifies the mass balance of the system. The energy supply side is exogenous of [[CIRCEE]]. [[CIRCEE]] is soft-linked to the {{abbr|Integrated Assessment Model|IAM}} model https://www.witchmodel.org/ from the RFF-CMCC European Institute on Economics and the Environment (EIEE) to assess the overall GHG mitigation potential of circular economy strategies.


* R Words coverage and implemented in the model
The government levies taxes, implements circular economy policies, and makes public expenses. In addition, the model considers trade flows between the domestic economy and the rest of the world.
CIRCEE provides a broad perspective on the economic and natural resource demand implications of a circular economy by integrating many different circular economy strategies. CIRCEE encompasses all the "R" strategies of circular economy.  


# <u>Recycle, Recove</u>r : substitute secondary (recycled) materials for primary (virgin) materials
The current geographical scope of [[CIRCEE]] is Japan, France and EU27. Data availability will determine which more OECD countries can be added to the model. However, users may add other countries themselves, provided there is enough data to calibrate the model.
# <u>Rethink, Repair, Reuse, Refurbish, Remanufacture</u> : substitute repaired and second-hand for newly produced goods,  replace new goods with services (sharing economy) and increase the utilization rate of long-lived goods (sharing economy), refurbish housing
# <u>Refuse</u> :
# <u>Reduce</u> : improve material productivity via technological change, substitute non-material inputs for materials, Green Design Product to increase longevity and recyclability of goods
* CE strategies and connexion with climate change mitigation.  
CIRCEE integrates exogenous instruments, depending on different narratives, to help the economy in its way to circularity :


1. <u>Substitute secondary (recycled) materials for primary (virgin) materials</u>
[[CIRCEE]] users can run the model for any desired number of years, using 2018 as the base year value. A longer time horizon can also be run to avoid any end-of-horizon effect, but 2080 is generally sufficient. Results are usually reported for the period 2019-2060. The model has a yearly time step. [[CIRCEE]] allows the users to choose between all SSPs but SSP3.


The model incorporate a tax on landfill waste, subsidies towards the recycling sector, mandatory recycling targets, green product design to increase the recyclability of goods, and Extended Producer Responsibility (EPR) fees.
===Model Development===


2. <u>Substitute repaired and second-hand for newly produced goods</u>
*Status: in progress.
* Environment: The model uses the open-source modelling platform [https://www.dynare.org dynare] which requires [https://www.mathworks.com/products/matlab.html matlab], [https://octave.org GNU Octave] or [https://julialang.org julia].
*Documentation: in progress. Not yet available.
*Source code: link available end of May 2024 (M24 in CIRCOMOD).


3. <u>Replace new goods with services (sharing economy)</u>
==Circular Economy Features ==


4. <u>Increase the utilization rate of long-lived goods (sharing economy)</u>
===R Words coverage and implemented in the model ===
[[File:R strategies and Policy instruments in CIRCEE.png|thumb|R strategies and Policy instruments in CIRCEE]]
[[CIRCEE]] offers a comprehensive outlook on the socio-economic-climatic consequences of implementing circular economy practices by integrating different strategies. At the macro level, [[CIRCEE]] encompasses the following R strategies. The first one is Recycle R8, which involves using secondary (recycled) materials instead of primary (virgin) materials. Increasing material circularity through strategies is key to the vision of a circular economy. The second one relates to Reuse R3, Repair R4 and Refurbish R5, which involves substituting newly produced goods with repaired or second-hand items to extend the lifespans of products, replacing new goods with services (such as in the sharing economy), and intensifying the use of long-lived goods (also in the sharing economy). The third encompasses Rethink R1, Reduce R2 and Refuse R0 which involves enhancing material productivity through technological advancements,, adopting Green Product Design to increase the durability and recyclability of goods, sharing products, and sufficiency behaviors. These strategies emphasize the significance of lowering material flows within the economy. Green product design is crucial in slowing down material flow by creating more durable and repairable goods. To support the economy's transition toward circularity, [[CIRCEE]] integrates various exogenous policies and economic instruments.


5. Refurbish housing
===CE strategies and connection with climate change mitigation.===
[[CIRCEE]] can activate various exogenous instruments, depending on different narratives, to help the economy to circularity. Each instrument has a direct (★) or indirect (☆) impact on GHG emissions. 


# <u>Refuse</u> :
{| class="wikitable" style="width:20em; text-align:center; float:right"
# <u>Reduce</u> : improve material productivity via technological change, substitute non-material inputs for materials, Green Design Product to increase longevity and recyclability of goods
!colspan="1"| Legend
* Synergies and trade-off between the R word in the context of the stylized model
|-
| ★: direct impact on GHG mitigation <br> : indirect impact on GHG mitigation
|}


=== Insights for Analytical Framework ===
1. <u>Substitute secondary (recycled) materials for primary (virgin) materials ([[Recycle (R8)]])</u>


* Key mechanisms and interactions within CE strategies that lead to changes in GHG emissions.
* Waste tax ★
* Tool exploration (demonstrating ideas before implementing them in large-scale quantitative models)
* Subsidies to recycling activities ☆
* Communication key CE dynamics (to the broader audience)
* The shock on the recyclability rate of waste ★
* Shock on the price differential between primary and secondary materials ★
* Shock on material prices ☆


=== Refinement and Integration ===
2. <u>Substitute repaired and second-hand for newly produced goods ([[Reuse (R3)|Re-use (R3)]], [[Repair (R4)]], Refurbish (R5))</u>


* Explain the iterative process of refining the stylized models by incorporating results emerging from other models
* Discount/no VAT for repairing services ☆
CIRCEE can be improved by including results from additional bottom-up models. These results can  be used to adjust the calibration of the model or integrate other circular economy techniques that are currently unavailable in CIRCEE due to insufficient data and literature on the subject. Furthermore, detailed bottom-up models for crucial sectors, such as transport and construction, can be connected to CIRCEE model to improve its capabilities in evaluating circular economy (CE) strategies.
* Repair bonus ☆
* Shock on second-hand goods demand ★
* Reduced transaction costs on second-hand markets ☆
* Lifestyle changes ★
* EPR fees to incentivize sustainable consumption decisions ★


* Discuss how the stylized models can be integrated into larger modeling efforts to assess the potential of CE in climate change mitigation more comprehensively.
3. <u>Replace new goods with services (sharing economy) ([[Rethink (R1)]])</u>


CIRCEE can be easily linked with other IAMs in a similar manner to WITCH. In particular, the primary output produced by CIRCEE that is utilized as an input in IAMs is the energy demand. From the energy demand, IAMs simulate the trajectory of energy prices of the energy system, and future GreenHouse Gases emissions that are fed into CIRCEE. From these, CIRCEE feds back to the IAM the new energy demand. The user would repeat this cycle until the two models converge, implying that the energy demand, energy prices, and greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions stabilizes. Note that if the material requirement of power generation technologies are present in the IAM, it can be linked to the material/waste stock and flows of CIRCEE.
* Lifestyle changes ★


* Future features of the model.
4. <u>Increase the utilization rate of long-lived goods (sharing economy) ([[Rethink (R1)]])</u>


* Shock on the utilization rate of durable goods ★
6. <u>Reduce the use of materials in production processes  ([[Rethink (R1)|Reduce (R2)]])</u>
* Waste tax ★
* Shock on the material loss during the production process of goods ★
* Shock on material productivity ★
7. <u>Substitute non-material inputs for materials ([[Refuse (R0)]])</u>
* Shock the substitution elasticity between non-resource resource inputs and resource inputs for key sectors ★
8. <u>Green Product Design to increase longevity of goods ([[Rethink (R1)]])</u>
* Decrease the depreciation rate of durable, semi-durable and capital goods ★
* EPR fees to incentivize green product design
9. <u>Reduce the consumption of certain goods ([[Reduce (R2)]])</u>
* Lifestyle changes ★
* EPR fees to incentivize sustainable consumption decisions ★
===Synergies and trade-off between the R-word in the context of the stylized model===
On the demand side, in response to exogenous incentives, households make inter-temporal trade-offs between different kinds of assets, such as newly-produced capital and durable goods and second-hand durable goods. Besides, households also make intra-temporal trade-offs between different kinds of goods and services. For instance, when a durable good such as a car reaches the end of its useful life, households have three options to continue consuming the energy service "mobility":
#Purchase a newly produced car, which requires new materials and energy inputs. However, the new car typically has higher energy efficiency than the old one.
#Continue consuming the energy service without purchasing a new car by engaging with the repairing service sector to extend the life of the old car. However, this option may have a negative impact on the overall energy efficiency of cars.
# Participate in the peer-to-peer sharing market to use a car, without directly owning it, jointly with energy.
#Participate in the second-hand car market, where they can purchase a used car that is not yet at the end of its useful service life.
On the supply side, sectors make intra-temporal trade-offs between different input mixes. For instance, firms may increase the use of recycled materials in their production process in response to external incentives promoting more circular behaviour. 
==Refinement, Integration, Future Development==
====Refinement process ====
The current version of CIRCEE does not account for endogenous green product design. Even though, behavioural plasticities can enable many different circular economy strategies, they also rely on the availability of design technology aiming at extending the lifespan of the products. Future versions should consider incorporating these aspects, especially considering that an increased EPR fee might lead producers to innovate in product design, favoring more sustainable and cost-effective production methods. This would necessitate a disaggregated representation of products in CIRCEE, focusing on key designs (repairability and durability) that dictate green product design, and could involve linking detailed, product-focused models with CIRCEE for a broader understanding of potential synergies and trade-offs between demand- and supply-side circular economy strategies.
In addition, incorporating endogenous technological advancements toward increasing material productivity and recycling quality  into the CIRCEE model depends on the accessibility of comprehensive and detailed data. This endogenous representation of technical change for material productivity and recycling quality in macroeconomic and integrated assessment models is, to our knowledge, nonexistent. To effectively integrate these advancements, the model requires open data on patents and R&D investments directed toward enhancing material productivity and the quality of recycled materials. Data on patents, and on their impact of material input mid in manufacturing processes, can reveal the direction of innovation and provide insight into future market trends regarding material efficiency and recycling technologies. Similarly, R \& D investment data can indicate the commitment and potential of industries to adopt such technologies. However, this also demands in-depth industrial surveys to assess the availability, cost, and efficacy of existing and emergent recycling technologies.
Furthermore, a better understanding of the dynamics between primary and secondary markets is vital. This includes understanding pricing mechanisms, demand and supply fluctuations, and substitution elasticity between primary (virgin) and secondary (recycled) materials. Clarity in how these markets interact and operate will provide a starting point for assessing how technological changes can affect market balances and recycling behaviors.
The advancement of CIRCEE depends on open access to comprehensive datasets and sufficient funding to study the multifaceted aspects of a circular economy, from the micro-level specifics of green product design to the macro-level implications for resource efficiency and economic growth. Securing dedicated funding is critical to support the extensive data collection and surveys necessary to develop these model components. As CIRCEE is an open-source model, it can greatly benefit from the support of a research community, which allow for such collaborative development through shared knowledge and resources. Such a model would provide policymakers with valuable insights, enabling them to make well-informed decisions that balance the various synergies and trade-offs of circular economy strategies.
==== Integration====
[[File:CIRCEE WITCH soft-linking.png|thumb|CIRCEE_WITCH soft-linking]]
CIRCEE can be easily similarly linked with other {{abbr|Integrated Assessment Model|IAM}}s to WITCH. In particular, the primary output of CIRCEE that is utilized as an input in {{abbr|Integrated Assessment Model|IAM}}s is the energy demand. From the energy demand, {{abbr|Integrated Assessment Model|IAM}}s simulate the trajectory of energy prices of the energy system and future GHG emissions that are fed into CIRCEE. From the new energy prices, CIRCEE feds back to the {{abbr|Integrated Assessment Model|IAM}} the new energy demand. The user would repeat this cycle until the two models converge, implying that the energy demand, energy prices, and GHG emissions stabilize. Note that if the material requirement of power generation technologies are present in the {{abbr|Integrated Assessment Model|IAM}}, it can be linked to the material/waste stock and flows of CIRCEE.
==== Future features of the model.====
# CIRCEE's current version includes exogenously technological change that is directed towards improving material productivity and recycling quality. A future version will include an endogenous representation of this technological change;
# CIRCEE's current version includes exogenously technological change that is directed towards improving material productivity and recycling quality. A future version will include an endogenous representation of this technological change;
# CIRCEE's stable version does not include second-hand markets, though an unstable version exists. The future stable version will enable the exchange of durable goods in second-hand markets;
# CIRCEE's stable version does not include second-hand markets, though an unstable version exists. The future stable version will enable the exchange of durable goods in second-hand markets;
# CIRCEE's current version includes exogenously digitalization via the narratives and shocks. The future version will include an endogenous representation of digitalization through technological change. This will primarily affect the sharing (energy) services sector and the robotization of the repairing sector. For instance, in the current version of CIRCEE, the increased use of capital compared to labor in the repairing services sector is an external factor introduced through narratives.
#A future version of CIRCEE will include endogenous green product design under the presence of circular services markets (repairing and sharing markets).  
 
== References ==

Latest revision as of 16:09, 2 May 2024

General Scope and Connection with Climate Mitigation

Introduction

Assessing the full potential of a circular economy requires a macro-level and integrated assessment approach that addresses the complex interdependencies and trade-offs between environmental, social, and economic objectives. Policy support, lifestyle changes, innovation, and new business models such as sharing and digitalization models are critical enablers for the transition to a circular economy, as well as a deep understanding of the underlying drivers and barriers. Also, it is important to understand the hypothetical synergies, benefits and trade-offs with implementing different circular economy strategies As these policies and lifestyle changes are vital in driving the transition toward a circular economy, understanding their implications is essential. Assessing the impact of a CE on socioeconomic systems remains a complex and challenging task for Integrated Assessment Models and the macroeconomic modeling community. Pauliuk et al. (2017) emphasize the necessity of incorporating industrial ecology system linkages into Integrated Assessment Models.

CIRCEE (CIRCular Energy Economy), developed by the RFF-CMCC European Institute on Economics and the Environment, addresses these challenges by developing a stylized DSGE model, soft-linked to the WITCH integrated assessment model and the LIFE model of Pettifor, Wilson, and Agnew (2023)[1], that integrates some industrial ecology aspects and lifestyle heterogeneity. Our framework captures the dynamic feedback loops between physical and economic systems and assesses the trade-offs and synergies between different sustainability objectives. The stylized model will serve as a starting point for the IAM community and help map CE strategies into existing climate scenarios.

Model Scope

The CIRCular Energy-Economy model

CIRCEE is a deterministic Dynamic and Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) model with resource stock/flow consistency. It incorporates some industrial ecology principles to evaluate how CE strategies and enablers can decrease future greenhouse gas emissions and enhance resource efficiency. First, the production-side of the economy follows a standard Constant Elasticity Substitution (CES) tree (see Figure) that combines different CES nests of inputs capital, labor, energy and materials. For accounting reasons, the CES nest of material inputs that combines primary materials and secondary materials is transformed as an additive function of the two inputs à la Mensbrugghe and Peters (2016). The material additive CES function allows us to verify the mass balance condition, and track material flows in a more precise manner. Each sector of final good production obey the rule of conservation of mass. The production structure of the economy is not changed, as it still produces from a standard nested CES function of capital, labor, energy and materials. Materials entering the system must equal to material leaving the system, whether it be in the form of good exports, additions to the in-use stocks or waste disposal. Second, we ensure that a 100% recycling scenario is not feasible, so that the economy cannot recover all recyclable waste. A ‘loss’ parameter, estimated from data about recycling activities, is attached to the use of recyclable waste in the production process of secondary materials to capture the environmental loss of materials during the recycling process. In addition, there is a natural obsolescence rate of durable goods, so that durable goods cannot be repaired on and off. Raw materials are extracted from abroad and are then used for material processing that feeds the production processes of final goods in terms of primary material inputs. These final goods are then consumed and disposed of at a certain time depending on the life of the goods. The waste generated by end-uses as well as production processes can be either landfilled/incinerated or recycled. Recycled/recovered materials can be fed back to the economy to ensure a higher circularity rate or exported abroad. I

**

Consumption tree in CIRCEE
Typology of households in CIRCEE from the LIFE model of Pettifor et al. (2023)

The economy is populated by heterogeneous households, producing sectors and a public authority.

On the demand side of the economy, three types of households are differentiated by their lifestyles and liquidity constraints. Households choose to consume different types of goods: non-durables, semi-durables and durable goods, and services : home-produced energy services, sharing energy services, and repairing services. They make intratemporal choices regarding the composition of their consumption basket (e.g. consuming sharing energy service rather than producing it at home) and intertemporal choices between different types of assets available to them (capital, durable and semi-durable goods). In CIRCEE, owners can make their durable goods available for rent to other individuals when they are not using them and are willing to rent them. The lifestyles are those outlined in the Pettifor, Wilson, and Agnew (2023)[1]. Low-carbon behaviors (lifestyles) are driven by cognitions and social/material contexts. They affect directly households' preferences in :

  • repairing durable goods rather than buying brand new
  • sharing a durable goods rather than buying brand new
  • lowering expenditures in durable goods and semi-durable goods (sufficiency)
CES tree for "new products" production sectors

On the economy's supply side, the economy is populated by eight sectors producing the following products: primary materials, secondary materials, non-durable goods, semi-durable goods, durable goods, capital goods, sharing energy services and repairing services. All goods and services sectors, except the repairing and sharing sector, produce from labour, capital, energy (electricity and fuels), and material (primary and secondary) inputs. The repairing sector only produces repairing/refurbishing services using labor and capital. The sharing sector rents part of the durable good stock owned by households, uses energy and labor to produce sharing services. Material processing firms use labor, capital, energy and raw or waste material inputs to produce primary and secondary materials. The production structure of the economy is economically and physically consistent, in the sense that it verifies the mass balance of the system. The energy supply side is exogenous of CIRCEE. CIRCEE is soft-linked to the IAM model https://www.witchmodel.org/ from the RFF-CMCC European Institute on Economics and the Environment (EIEE) to assess the overall GHG mitigation potential of circular economy strategies.

The government levies taxes, implements circular economy policies, and makes public expenses. In addition, the model considers trade flows between the domestic economy and the rest of the world.

The current geographical scope of CIRCEE is Japan, France and EU27. Data availability will determine which more OECD countries can be added to the model. However, users may add other countries themselves, provided there is enough data to calibrate the model.

CIRCEE users can run the model for any desired number of years, using 2018 as the base year value. A longer time horizon can also be run to avoid any end-of-horizon effect, but 2080 is generally sufficient. Results are usually reported for the period 2019-2060. The model has a yearly time step. CIRCEE allows the users to choose between all SSPs but SSP3.

Model Development

  • Status: in progress.
  • Environment: The model uses the open-source modelling platform dynare which requires matlab, GNU Octave or julia.
  • Documentation: in progress. Not yet available.
  • Source code: link available end of May 2024 (M24 in CIRCOMOD).

Circular Economy Features

R Words coverage and implemented in the model

R strategies and Policy instruments in CIRCEE

CIRCEE offers a comprehensive outlook on the socio-economic-climatic consequences of implementing circular economy practices by integrating different strategies. At the macro level, CIRCEE encompasses the following R strategies. The first one is Recycle R8, which involves using secondary (recycled) materials instead of primary (virgin) materials. Increasing material circularity through strategies is key to the vision of a circular economy. The second one relates to Reuse R3, Repair R4 and Refurbish R5, which involves substituting newly produced goods with repaired or second-hand items to extend the lifespans of products, replacing new goods with services (such as in the sharing economy), and intensifying the use of long-lived goods (also in the sharing economy). The third encompasses Rethink R1, Reduce R2 and Refuse R0 which involves enhancing material productivity through technological advancements,, adopting Green Product Design to increase the durability and recyclability of goods, sharing products, and sufficiency behaviors. These strategies emphasize the significance of lowering material flows within the economy. Green product design is crucial in slowing down material flow by creating more durable and repairable goods. To support the economy's transition toward circularity, CIRCEE integrates various exogenous policies and economic instruments.

CE strategies and connection with climate change mitigation.

CIRCEE can activate various exogenous instruments, depending on different narratives, to help the economy to circularity. Each instrument has a direct (★) or indirect (☆) impact on GHG emissions.

Legend
★: direct impact on GHG mitigation
☆: indirect impact on GHG mitigation

1. Substitute secondary (recycled) materials for primary (virgin) materials (Recycle (R8))

  • Waste tax ★
  • Subsidies to recycling activities ☆
  • The shock on the recyclability rate of waste ★
  • Shock on the price differential between primary and secondary materials ★
  • Shock on material prices ☆

2. Substitute repaired and second-hand for newly produced goods (Re-use (R3), Repair (R4), Refurbish (R5))

  • Discount/no VAT for repairing services ☆
  • Repair bonus ☆
  • Shock on second-hand goods demand ★
  • Reduced transaction costs on second-hand markets ☆
  • Lifestyle changes ★
  • EPR fees to incentivize sustainable consumption decisions ★

3. Replace new goods with services (sharing economy) (Rethink (R1))

  • Lifestyle changes ★

4. Increase the utilization rate of long-lived goods (sharing economy) (Rethink (R1))

  • Shock on the utilization rate of durable goods ★

6. Reduce the use of materials in production processes (Reduce (R2))

  • Waste tax ★
  • Shock on the material loss during the production process of goods ★
  • Shock on material productivity ★

7. Substitute non-material inputs for materials (Refuse (R0))

  • Shock the substitution elasticity between non-resource resource inputs and resource inputs for key sectors ★

8. Green Product Design to increase longevity of goods (Rethink (R1))

  • Decrease the depreciation rate of durable, semi-durable and capital goods ★
  • EPR fees to incentivize green product design

9. Reduce the consumption of certain goods (Reduce (R2))

  • Lifestyle changes ★
  • EPR fees to incentivize sustainable consumption decisions ★

Synergies and trade-off between the R-word in the context of the stylized model

On the demand side, in response to exogenous incentives, households make inter-temporal trade-offs between different kinds of assets, such as newly-produced capital and durable goods and second-hand durable goods. Besides, households also make intra-temporal trade-offs between different kinds of goods and services. For instance, when a durable good such as a car reaches the end of its useful life, households have three options to continue consuming the energy service "mobility":

  1. Purchase a newly produced car, which requires new materials and energy inputs. However, the new car typically has higher energy efficiency than the old one.
  2. Continue consuming the energy service without purchasing a new car by engaging with the repairing service sector to extend the life of the old car. However, this option may have a negative impact on the overall energy efficiency of cars.
  3. Participate in the peer-to-peer sharing market to use a car, without directly owning it, jointly with energy.
  4. Participate in the second-hand car market, where they can purchase a used car that is not yet at the end of its useful service life.

On the supply side, sectors make intra-temporal trade-offs between different input mixes. For instance, firms may increase the use of recycled materials in their production process in response to external incentives promoting more circular behaviour.

Refinement, Integration, Future Development

Refinement process

The current version of CIRCEE does not account for endogenous green product design. Even though, behavioural plasticities can enable many different circular economy strategies, they also rely on the availability of design technology aiming at extending the lifespan of the products. Future versions should consider incorporating these aspects, especially considering that an increased EPR fee might lead producers to innovate in product design, favoring more sustainable and cost-effective production methods. This would necessitate a disaggregated representation of products in CIRCEE, focusing on key designs (repairability and durability) that dictate green product design, and could involve linking detailed, product-focused models with CIRCEE for a broader understanding of potential synergies and trade-offs between demand- and supply-side circular economy strategies.

In addition, incorporating endogenous technological advancements toward increasing material productivity and recycling quality  into the CIRCEE model depends on the accessibility of comprehensive and detailed data. This endogenous representation of technical change for material productivity and recycling quality in macroeconomic and integrated assessment models is, to our knowledge, nonexistent. To effectively integrate these advancements, the model requires open data on patents and R&D investments directed toward enhancing material productivity and the quality of recycled materials. Data on patents, and on their impact of material input mid in manufacturing processes, can reveal the direction of innovation and provide insight into future market trends regarding material efficiency and recycling technologies. Similarly, R \& D investment data can indicate the commitment and potential of industries to adopt such technologies. However, this also demands in-depth industrial surveys to assess the availability, cost, and efficacy of existing and emergent recycling technologies.

Furthermore, a better understanding of the dynamics between primary and secondary markets is vital. This includes understanding pricing mechanisms, demand and supply fluctuations, and substitution elasticity between primary (virgin) and secondary (recycled) materials. Clarity in how these markets interact and operate will provide a starting point for assessing how technological changes can affect market balances and recycling behaviors.

The advancement of CIRCEE depends on open access to comprehensive datasets and sufficient funding to study the multifaceted aspects of a circular economy, from the micro-level specifics of green product design to the macro-level implications for resource efficiency and economic growth. Securing dedicated funding is critical to support the extensive data collection and surveys necessary to develop these model components. As CIRCEE is an open-source model, it can greatly benefit from the support of a research community, which allow for such collaborative development through shared knowledge and resources. Such a model would provide policymakers with valuable insights, enabling them to make well-informed decisions that balance the various synergies and trade-offs of circular economy strategies.

Integration

CIRCEE_WITCH soft-linking

CIRCEE can be easily similarly linked with other IAMs to WITCH. In particular, the primary output of CIRCEE that is utilized as an input in IAMs is the energy demand. From the energy demand, IAMs simulate the trajectory of energy prices of the energy system and future GHG emissions that are fed into CIRCEE. From the new energy prices, CIRCEE feds back to the IAM the new energy demand. The user would repeat this cycle until the two models converge, implying that the energy demand, energy prices, and GHG emissions stabilize. Note that if the material requirement of power generation technologies are present in the IAM, it can be linked to the material/waste stock and flows of CIRCEE.

Future features of the model.

  1. CIRCEE's current version includes exogenously technological change that is directed towards improving material productivity and recycling quality. A future version will include an endogenous representation of this technological change;
  2. CIRCEE's stable version does not include second-hand markets, though an unstable version exists. The future stable version will enable the exchange of durable goods in second-hand markets;
  3. A future version of CIRCEE will include endogenous green product design under the presence of circular services markets (repairing and sharing markets).

References

  1. 1.0 1.1 Hazel Pettifor, Maureen Agnew, Charlie Wilson. A framework for measuring and modelling low-carbon lifestyles, Global Environmental Change, Volume 82, 2023, 102739, ISSN 0959-3780, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2023.102739.